THE BRITISH EMPIRE AND GLOBALIZATION: A FORUM
Niall Ferguson, P.J. Marshall, Robert E. Lucas, Jr., Andrew Porter, and Andrew J. Bacevich

With two books and a British television series, Niall Ferguson has placed a spotlight on the history of the British Empire and its relevance for making sense of the contemporary world. Here he considers the empire’s impact on the global economy. P.J. Marshall, Robert E. Lucas, Jr., Andrew Porter, and Andrew Bacevich respond to his essay, followed by Ferguson’s concluding reply.             

British Imperialism Revisited: The Costs and Benefits of “Anglobalization
by Niall Ferguson       
    

It is fair to say that recent economic history has not been kind to the British Empire. According to one influential school of thought, late 19th-century capital exports to the country’s numerous colonies diverted resources away from the modernization of British industry. Some scholars have questioned whether it was even economically rational for the investors themselves.[1] Patrick O’Brien has argued that after around 1846 Britain could have withdrawn from empire with impunity, and reaped a “decolonization dividend” in the form of a 25% tax cut. The money taxpayers would have saved as a result of a Victorian decolonization could have been spent on electricity, cars, and consumer durables, thus encouraging industrial modernization at home.[2]

Such negative assessments of Britain’s relationship to the empire sit somewhat uneasily alongside the large “nationalist” literature on the impact of empire on Britain’s colonies, notably India. In the words of B. R. Tomlinson, “the suggestion remains that British rule did not leave a substantial legacy of wealth, health, or happiness to the majority of the subjects of the Commonwealth.”[3] Numerous authors have insisted that the principal consequence of British rule in the Indian subcontinent was a legacy of “underdevelopment.” Can it really be that the empire was economically bad for both Britain and her colonies? By drawing on the recent economic literature on globalization, past and present, this essay argues otherwise.

* * *

In an influential paper published in 1995, Jeffrey Sachs and A. M. Warner demonstrated conclusively that one of the principal reasons for widening international inequality in the 1970s and 1980s was protectionism in less developed economies. In their words, “open economies tend to converge [on the developed economies], but closed economies do not. The lack of convergence in recent decades results from the fact that the poorer countries have been closed to the world.” When they compared per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) growth among developing countries, they found that “the open economies grew at 4.49% per year, and the closed countries grew at 0.69% per year.” Sachs and Warner’s findings have been widely interpreted as making the case for present-day “globalization.” However, their findings also have important historical implications. As the authors note, in the previous era of globalization—conventionally seen as the period from the mid 19th century until the First World War—economic openness was imposed by colonial powers (principally, of course, Britain) not only on Asian and African colonies but also on South America and even Japan.[4]

A similar point can be made with respect to flows of labor. Jeffrey Williamson and others have emphasized the importance of international migration (or the restrictions on it) in determining the extent of international inequality. The more free movement there is of labor, the more international income levels will tend to converge. One reason that modern globalization is associated with high levels of inequality is that there are so many restrictions on the free movement of labor from less developed to developed countries.[5] This too has obvious implications for the history of the British Empire, which actively promoted emigration to at least some of its colonies, and certainly did nothing to heed the migration of British people wherever they wished to go.

Consider also the evidence on international capital flows, another key component of globalization. Development economists have spent many decades trying to work out how to raise the level of investment in backward agrarian societies. The most obvious solution has been for them to import capital from where it is plentiful, namely the developed world. According to the simple classical model of the world economy, this should happen naturally: capital should flow from developed to less developed economies, where returns are likely to be higher. But as Robert Lucas pointed out, with respect to the United States and India in the 1970s, this does not seem to happen in practice.[6] Although some measures of international financial integration seem to suggest that the 1990s saw bigger cross-border capital flows than the 1890s, in reality most of today’s overseas investment goes on within the developed world. In 1996 only 28% of foreign direct investment went to developing countries; by 2000 their share was less than a fifth. The overwhelming majority takes place between the United States, the European Union, and Japan. Investors in the developed world prefer to invest in countries which already have high levels of per capita GDP, which is one reason why increased capital flows in recent decades seem to have been associated with widening international inequalities.

As Michael Clemens and Jeffrey Williamson have shown, there was something of a “Lucas effect” in the first era of globalization, in that “about two-thirds of [British capital exports] went to the labor-scarce New World where only a tenth of the world’s population lived, and only about a quarter of it went to labor-abundant Asia and Africa where almost two-thirds of the world’s population lived.”[7] Nevertheless, the share of British capital going to poorer countries was still significantly larger than it is today. According to Maurice Obstfeld and Alan Taylor, in 1997 only around 5% of the world stock of capital was invested in countries with per capita incomes of 20% or less of U.S. per capita GDP. In 1913 the figure was 25%. They also estimate the share of developing countries in total international liabilities at 11% in 1995, compared with 33% in 1900 and 47% in 1938. Those figures are at least suggestive of the possibility that the existence of formal empire encouraged investors to put their money in less developed economies (see Figure 1).[8]

Figure 1Figure 1

Finally, we need to consider recent empirical work on the institutional and political preconditions for growth. In a cross-country study of postwar economic growth, Robert Barro concluded that there were six significant variables that were likely to influence a country’s economic performance. The first was the provision of secondary and higher education; the second was the provision of health care, since there is a correlation between growth and life expectancy; the third was the promotion of birth control; the fourth was the avoidance of “non-productive government expenditures,” since “big government is bad for growth”; the fifth was the enforcement of the rule of law; and the sixth was the avoidance of inflation above 10% per annum.[9] David Landes, in his Wealth and Poverty of Nations, has come to similar conclusions, arguing that “the ideal growth-and-development” government would: secure rights of private property; secure rights of personal liberty; enforce rights of contract; and provide stability and fairness in an efficient, moderate fashion.[10]

It requires only a passing familiarity with the nature of British colonial administration to recognize that at least some of these were among its defining characteristics. To be sure, British colonial rule was not democratic (outside the “white dominions”—Canada, Australia, and New Zealand). But as both Barro and Landes observe, democracy does not correlate especially closely with economic performance.

There is a significant discrepancy between the modern literature on economic growth and the historical consensus that the British Empire was economically deleterious. A striking number of the things currently recommended by economists to developing countries were in fact imposed by British rule. There was, as Alan Taylor has suggested, a “London consensus” not unlike the “Washington consensus” of our own time, with the difference that the International Monetary Fund cannot rely on the services of the Royal Navy to enforce its recommendations. Unless the economists have got it seriously wrong, there is at least a prima facie case that the British Empire was economically beneficial, not only to Britain herself, but also to her empire—and perhaps even to the world economy as a whole.

* * *

Let us begin with world trade and tariffs. In an ideal world, of course, free trade would be naturally occurring. But history and political economy tell us that it is not. For most of the 19th century, free trade spread because of Britain’s power more than Britain’s example. From the 1840s until the 1930s, the British political elite and electorate remained wedded to the principle of laissez faire, laissez passer—and the practice of “cheap bread.” That meant that—certainly from the 1870s—British tariffs were significantly lower than those of her European neighbors; it also meant that tariffs in much of the British Empire were also kept low. Abandoning formal control over Britain ’s colonies would almost certainly have led to higher tariffs being erected against British exports in their markets, and perhaps other forms of trade discrimination.

The evidence for this need not be purely hypothetical: it is manifest in the highly protectionist policies adopted by the United States and India after they secured independence, as well as in the tariff regimes adopted by Britain ’s imperial rivals France, Germany, and Russia after the late 1870s. Whether one looks at the duties on primary products or manufactures, Britain was the least protectionist of the imperial powers. In 1913 average tariff rates on imported manufactures were 13% in Germany, over 20% in France, 44% in the United States, and 84% in Russia. In Britain they were zero.

According to Michael Edelstein, the economic benefit to Britain of enforcing free trade could have been anywhere between 1.8 and 6.5% of the Gross National Product (GNP).[11] But what about the benefit to the rest of the world? In the words of Sir John Graham, Britainwas “the great Emporium of the commerce of the World.” Its domestic market and much of its empire were more or less open to all comers to sell their wares as best they could. The evidence that Britain ’s continued policy of free trade was beneficial, in a protectionist world, to her colonies seems unequivocal. Between 1871-75 and 1925-29, the colonies’ share of Britain’s imports rose from a quarter to a third. More generally, as Jeffrey Williamson has argued, it was (mainly British) colonial authorities that resisted protectionist backlashes to the dramatic falls in factor prices caused by late 19th-century globalization.[12]

In the same way, there would not have been so much international mobility of labor—and hence so much global convergence of incomes before 1914—without the British Empire. True, the independent United States was always the most attractive destination for 19th-century emigrants. But as American restrictions in immigration increased, the significance of the white dominions—Canada, Australia, and New Zealand—as a destination for British emigrants grew markedly, attracting around 59% of all British emigrants between 1900 and 1914, 75% between 1915 and 1949, and 82% between 1949 and 1963. Nor should we lose sight of the vast numbers of Asians who left India and Chinain the 19th century to work as indentured laborers, many of them on British plantations and mines. Perhaps as many as 1.6 million Indians emigrated under this system, which lay somewhere between free and unfree labor. There is no question that the majority of them suffered great hardship; many indeed might have been better off staying at home. But once again we cannot pretend that this mobilization of cheap and probably underemployed Asians to grow rubber or dig gold had no economic significance (see Figure 2).

Figure 2

Figure 2

Similar arguments may be advanced about Britain's role as a capital exporter. As is well known, from the mid-19th until the mid-20th century, Britain acted as the world’s banker, channeling colossal sums of British (and other European) savings overseas. By 1914 total British assets overseas amounted to somewhere between £3.1 and £4.5 billion, while the British GDP was £2.5 billion. Compared with the other major capital exporters of the period, Britainsent a remarkably high proportion of her savings to overseas economies. To be sure, around 45% of British investment went to the United States and the dominions. But 16% of British foreign investment went to Asiaand 13% to Africa, compared with just 6% to the rest of Europe. Taking British investment as a whole, between 1865 and 1914, as much went to Africa, Asia, and Latin America (29.6%) as to the UK itself (31.8%). This pattern was surprisingly little changed by the effects of the First World War and the Great Depression. As late as 1938, around 18% of British overseas assets were in Asia, and 11% in Africa. As is well known, British investment in developing economies principally took the form of portfolio investment in infrastructure, especially railways. But the British also sank considerable (and not easily calculable) sums directly into plantations to produce new cash crops like tea, cotton, indigo, and rubber. 

Investing money in faraway places is risky: what economists call “informational asymmetries” are generally greater the further the lender is from the borrower. Less developed economies also tend to be rather more susceptible to economic, social, and political crises. Why then were British investors willing to risk such an exceptionally high proportion of their savings by purchasing securities or other assets overseas? One possible answer is that the adoption of the gold standard by developing economies offered investors a “good housekeeping seal of approval.” To be precise, as Michael Bordo has shown, going onto gold reduced the yield on government gold-denominated bonds by around 40 basis points.[13] It is certainly the case that before 1914 adoption of the gold standard was as good a way of obtaining cheap loans as membership in the British Empire—though it must be remembered that many countries went onto gold (which was, after all, a sterling standard devised in London) precisely because they were British colonies.

Yet there is a need to distinguish here between anticipated and actual returns on overseas investments. For the period 1850 to 1914, anticipated (ex ante) returns were not significantly lower on colonial bonds than they were on other foreign bonds. But the same cannot be said of the actual (ex post) returns. If one takes an average of the three colonial countries in the sample, the anticipated yield was 5.3%, compared with 4.7% for the three South American countries. But the actual returns were significantly different: 4.7% as against 2.9%. This helps explain why, when the same countries returned to the bond market in the interwar years, they paid significantly different risk premia. On average, the ex ante returns Latin American borrowers had to offer investors were 270 basis points higher than those on new colonial issues. Even so, actual returns on Latin American bonds were once again worse than expected and worse than those on colonial bonds (see Figure 3).

Figure 3Figure 3

In other words, experience showed that money invested in a de jure British colony such as India, or in a colony in all but name like Egypt, was more secure than money invested in an independent, albeit informally “colonized” country such as Argentina. This was because the commitment to gold was a “contingent commitment”; it was essentially voluntary and could be suspended in the event of an emergency such as a war.[14] Gold standard members who were otherwise sovereign states could not only suspend gold convertibility of their currencies; they could also default on their debts. To varying degrees and at various times, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Japan, Russia, and Turkey all did precisely that. Membership in the empire was quite different. British colonies were unlikely to suspend convertibility and not much more likely to default than Britain herself. By the 1920s, membership in the empire was therefore confirmed as a better “good housekeeping seal of approval” than gold (see Figure 4).

Figure 4Figure 4

That imperial membership offered better security to investors than mere adoption of the gold anchor is not surprising. There were a variety of explicit legal guarantees offered by the Colonial Loans Act (1899) and the Colonial Stock Act (1900), which gave colonial bonds the same “trustee status” as the benchmark British government perpetual bond, the “consol.” Over and above that, there was the cast-iron commitment of colonial governors and administrators to the principles of Gladstonian finance. It was inconceivable, declared the governor of the Gold Coast in 1933, that the interest due on Gold Coast bonds should be compulsorily reduced: why should British investors “accept yet another burden for the relief of persons in another country who have enjoyed all the benefits but will not accept their obligation”? Even colonial constitutions had been drafted with at least one eye on creditor preferences.[15]

This therefore explains why an increasing share of British overseas investment ended up going to the empire after the First World War. In the period from 1856 to 1914, around two-fifths (39%) of British overseas capital went to the empire, compared with three-fifths (61%) to the rest of the world. But after the First World War, the tables turned. Between 1919 and 1938, the empire got two-thirds, the rest got a third. Nor is it surprising that more than three-quarters of all foreign capital invested in sub-Saharan Africa was invested in British colonies (see Figure 5).[16]

Figure 5
Figure 5

P. J. Cain and A. G. Hopkins lay great emphasis, in their path-breaking history of British imperialism, on the dominant role played by the City of London, with its ethos of “gentlemanly capitalism.” In both the formal and the informal empire, they argue, finance came first, and British export industries a poor second. They do not address how the policy of prioritizing overseas investment affected the rest of the world. On the strength of the evidence I’ve presented here, it seems reasonable to conclude that it offered at least the opportunity of economic convergence. For in order to ensure that loans to developing economies were repaid, British policy makers were prepared to go to considerable lengths, ultimately allowing a system of differential tariffs to evolve which gave colonial manufacturers easier access to the British “home” market than British manufacturers enjoyed to colonial markets.

Intention and outcome are two different things. The British did not see the economic development of Asia and Africa as their primary concern, though they sometimes paid lip service to the idea. As we shall see, they would have acted rather differently in India, if development had been the paramount objective. Nevertheless, the intended policy of financial rather than industrial domination of the world economy had secondary positive outcomes alongside the primary outcome of ensuring that investors got their interest and principal. Under the right circumstances, this policy was conducive to rapid economic growth on the periphery—more so than a policy which would have put the interests of British industrial exports first.

* * *

The results of “Anglobalization” were in many ways astounding. The combination of free trade, mass migration, and unprecedented overseas investment propelled large parts of the British Empire to the forefront of world economic development. In terms of the production of manufactured goods per head of population, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand ranked higher than Germany in 1913. Between 1820 and 1950, their economies were the fastest growing in the world. Per capita GDP grew more rapidly in Canada than the United States between 1820 and 1913 (see Figure 6).

Figure 6Figure 6

But the performance of the dominions was not matched in the rest of the Empire and least of all in Asia. Why was Indian economic performance so much worse than that of the dominions? India attracted £286 million of capital raised in London between 1865 and 1914—18% of the total placed in the empire, second only to Canada. Yet Indian per capita GDP grew at a miserably slow rate. Between 1857 and 1947—between the Mutiny and Independence, in other words—Indian per capita GDP grew by just 19%, compared with an increase in Britain of 134%. The chart shows that between 1820 and 1950, it grew at a mere 0.12% per annum—barely at all by the standards of the “white” empire, and slow even by comparison with Africa.

The nationalist explanation for Indian “underdevelopment” under British rule has four essential components. First, the British de-industrialized India by opening it to factory-produced textiles from Lancashire, whose manufacturers were initially protected from Indian competition until they had established a technological lead. Second, they imposed excessive and regressive taxation. Third, they “drained” capital from India, even manipulating the rupee-sterling exchange rate to their own advantage. Finally, they did next to nothing to alleviate the famines that these policies caused. One recent historian has gone so far as to speak of “Late Victorian Holocausts” in the 1870s and 1890s.[17] This negative view of the British role in India—which can be traced back to Dadabhai Naoroji’s Poverty and Un-British Rule in India (1901)—continues to enjoy wide currency.[18]

No doubt it benefited the Indian economy little to maintain one of the world’s largest standing armies as a mercenary force. Yet recent research casts doubt on other aspects of the nationalist critique. Tirthankar Roy has shown that the destruction of jobs in the Indian textile industry was probably inevitable, regardless of who ruled India, and that an equal if not greater number of new jobs were created in new economic sectors built up by the British. Even in the case of textiles, by the 1920s the Government of India was clearly giving preference to Indian manufacturers over Lancashire’s mills. Roy also casts doubt on the idea that taxation under the British was excessive, showing that the land tax burden fell from around 10% of net output in the 1850s to 5% by the 1930s.[19] The supposed “drain” of capital from Indiato Britain turns out to have been comparatively modest: only “about 0.9-1.3% of Indian national income from 1868 to the 1930s,” according to one estimate of the export surplus (which was what nationalists usually had in mind).[20] In any case, so far as the Home Charges were concerned, “a great deal of government expenditure was in fact incurred for services that India needed but could not supply on her own.” Finally, “the prospect of devastating famines once every few years was inherent in India’s ecology . . . . Famines were primarily environmental in origin” and after 1900 the problem was alleviated by the greater integration of the Indian market for foodstuffs. The Bengal famine of 1943 arose precisely because improvements introduced under British rule collapsed under the strain of the war.[21]

Moreover, British rule had some distinctly positive effects. It greatly increased the importance of trade, from between 1-2% of national income to more than 20% by 1913. The British created an integrated Indian market: they unified weights, measures, and the currency, abolished transit duties and introduced a “legal framework [which] promoted private property rights and contract law more explicitly.” They invested substantially in repairing and enlarging the country’s ancient irrigation system: between 1891 and 1938, the acreage under irrigation more than doubled. As is well known, the British transformed the Indian system of communications, introducing a postal and telegraph system, deploying steamships on internal waterways and building more than 40,000 miles of railway track (roughly five times the amount constructed in Chinain the same period). The railway network alone employed more than a million people by the last decade of British rule. Finally, there was a significant increase in financial intermediation. As Roy concludes:

The railways, the ports, major irrigation systems, the telegraph, sanitation and medical care, the universities, the postal system, the courts of law, were assets India could not believably have acquired in such extent and quality had it not developed close political links with Britain . . . . British rule appears to have done far more than what its predecessor regimes and contemporary Indian regimes were able to do.[22]

By comparison with the other major Asian empire—China, which remained under Asian political control—Indiafared well. The Chinese economy shrank, even if some of its troubles can doubtless be attributed to the disruptive influence of informal European imperialism.

The explanation for the disappointing impact of these improvements on per capita incomes lies not in British exploitation, but rather in the insufficient scale of British interference in the Indian economy. The British expanded Indian education—but not enough to make a real impact on the quality of human capital. The number of educated Indians may have increased sevenfold between 1881 and 1941, but the proportion of the population with primary or secondary educations was far below European rates (2% in India in 1913, compared with 16% in Britain). The British invested in India—but not enough to pull most Indian farmers up off the base line of subsistence, and certainly not enough to compensate for the pitifully low level of indigenous net capital formation, worsened by the custom of hoarding gold. The British built hospitals and banks—but not enough of them to make significant improvements in public health and credit networks. These were sins of omission more than commission. Unfortunately for Indians, the nationalists who came to power in 1947 drew almost completely the wrong conclusions about what had gone wrong under British rule, embarking instead on a program of sub-Soviet state-led autarky whose achievement was to widen still further the gap between Indian and British incomes, which reached its widest historic extent in 1973.

* * *

Economic historians continue to debate the causes of the “great divergence” of economic fortunes which has characterized the last half millennium. In this debate, the role of colonialism—and specifically the British Empire—has a crucial role to play. If geography, climate, and disease provide a sufficient explanation for the widening of global inequalities, then the policies and institutions exported by British imperialism were of marginal importance; the agricultural, commercial, and industrial technologies developed in Europe from 1700 onward were bound to work better in temperate regions with good access to sea routes. However, if the key to economic success lies in the adoption of legal, financial, and political institutions favorable to technical innovation and capital accumulation—regardless of location, mean temperature, and longevity—then it matters a great deal that by the end of the 19th century a quarter of the world was under British rule. According to Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson, “societies where colonialism led to the establishment of good institutions prospered relative to those where colonialism imposed extractive institutions.”[23] Where colonizing powers encountered relatively advanced economies—as measured by the density of population—the institutions imposed were essentially those of plunder and exaction. These institutions were unlikely to foster long-run growth, and indeed had the effect of impoverishing the conquered. But in less densely populated, poorer societies, the colonizers had to start more or less from scratch. That was why Western European style institutions were more likely to be introduced in North America or Australia than in Central America.

In all likelihood, the dichotomy between geography and institutions is a false one. The British settled in large numbers in temperate zones, taking their institutions with them; in the tropics, they preferred to rely on monopoly companies and plantations run in (unequal) partnership with indigenous elites. But by the last third of the 19th century this distinction had faded somewhat. Even in the tropics, the British endeavored to introduce the institutions that they regarded as essential to prosperity: free trade, free (and indeed forced) migration, infrastructural investment, balanced budgets, sound money, the rule of law, and incorrupt administration. If the results were much less impressive in Africa and India than they were in the colonies of British settlement, that was because even the best institutions work less well in landlocked, excessively hot, or disease-ridden places. There, the investments which were needed to overcome geography, climate, and their attendant deleterious effects on human capital were beyond the imaginings of colonial rulers schooled in the Gladstonian fiscal tradition.

Perhaps they are beyond our imaginings, too. It is far from clear that the very different policies adopted by post-independence governments and international agencies have been more successful. A simple calculation of the ratio of British per capita GDP to that of forty-one former colonies is instructive. Between 1960 and 1990 the gap between the British and their former subjects narrowed in just fourteen cases (see Figure 7).[24] While it is convenient for contemporary rulers in countries like Zimbabwe to blame their problems on the “legacy of British rule,” the reality is that British rule was on balance conducive to economic growth. Tragically, most post-independence governments have failed to improve on it.

Figure 7Figure 7

©Niall Ferguson 2003

Niall Ferguson is professor of financial history at New York University’s  Stern Business School and senior research fellow at Jesus College, Oxford University. His most recent books are Empire: The Rise and Demise of the British World Order and Its Lessons for Global Power (Basic Books, 2003) and Empire: How Britain Made the Modern World (Allen Lane, 2003), the latter of which was published to coincide with a television history of the British Empire broadcast in January 2003. 



[1] Lance E. Davis and R.A. Huttenback, Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The Political Economy of British Imperialism, 1860-1912 (Cambridge University Press, 1986), 107.

[2] Patrick K. O’Brien, “Imperialism and the Rise and Decline of the British Economy, 1688-1989,” New Left Review 238 (1999): 56, 65f, 75.

[3] B. R. Tomlinson, “Imperialism and After: The Economy of the Empire on the Periphery,” in Judith M. Brown and Wm.Roger Louis, eds., The Oxford History of the British Empire, vol. IV:  The Twentieth Century (Oxford University Press, 1999), 375.

[4] Jeffrey D. Sachs and A. M. Warner, “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1995): 6-10, 35. 

[5] Jeffrey G. Williamson, “Winners and Losers Over Two Centuries of Globalization,” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper 9161 (2002).

[6]For a discussion, see Michael A. Clemens and Jeffrey G. Williamson, “Where did British Capital Go? Fundamentals, Failures, and the Lucas Paradox: 1870-1913,” NBER Working Paper 8028 (2000).

[7] Clemens and Williamson, “Where did British Foreign Capital Go?”

[8] Maurice Obstfeld and Alan M. Taylor, “Globalization and Capital Markets,” NBER Working Paper 8846 (2002): 60, figure 10; table 2. However, Obstfeld and Taylor follow Michael D. Bordo in identifying the spread of the gold standard as the explanation: Maurice Obstfeld, and Alan M. Taylor, “Sovereign Risk, Credibility and the Gold Standard: 1870-1913 versus 1925-31,” NBER Working Paper 9345 (2002).

[9] Robert J. Barro, “Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study,” NBER Working Paper 5698 (1996).

[10]David S. Landes, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations (Norton, 1998), 217f.

[11] Michael Edelstein, “Imperialism: Cost and Benefit,” in Roderick Floud and Donald McCloskey, eds., The Economic History of Britain since 1700, vol. II: 1860-1939, 2nd ed. (Cambridge University Press, 1994), 205. 

[12]Jeffrey G. Williamson, “Land, Labor, and Globalization in the Pre-Industrial Third World,” NBER Working Paper 7784 (2000).

[13] The definitive statement is in Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff, “The Gold Standard as a ‘Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval,’” Journal of Economic History 56 (1996), reprinted in Bordo, The Gold Standard and Related Regimes (Cambridge University Press, 1999), 149-178.

[14] Michael D. Bordo and Finn E. Kydland, “The Gold Standard as a Commitment Mechanism,” in Tamim Bayoumi, Barry Eichengreen, and Mark P. Taylor, eds., Modern Perspectives on the Gold Standard (Cambridge University Press, 1996), 55-100.

[15] P. J. Cain and A. G. Hopkins, British Imperialism, 1688-2000, 2nd ed. (Longman, 2001), 439, 570, 584f, 233.

[16] Cain and Hopkins, British Imperialism, 439, 567.

[17]Mike Davis, Late Victorian Holocausts: El Nino Famines and the Making of the Third World (Verso, 2001).

[18] See e.g. Tapan Raychaudhuri, “British Rule in India: An Assessment,” in P. J. Marshall, ed., The Cambridge Illustrated History of the British Empire (Cambridge University Press, 1996), 361-4; Simon Schama, A History of Britain, vol. III: The Fate of Empire (Miramax, 2002), esp. 359-64.

[19] Tirthankar Roy, The Economic History of India , 1857-1947 (Oxford UniversityPress, 2000), 42ff, 250.

[20] Angus Maddison, The World Economy: A Millennium Perspective (OECD, 2001), table 2-21b.

[21] Roy, Economic History, 241, 22, 219f., 254, 285, 294.

[22] Roy, Economic History, 32-6, 215, 258-263, 46f.

[23] Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson, “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution,” NBER Working Paper 8460 (2001): 5.

[24] They are: Lesotho, Pakistan, Egypt, Botswana, Malaysia, Malta, Barbados, Cyprus, Israel, Ireland, Singapore, Hong Kong, Canada, and the United States: figures from Maddison, World Economy.